稅收、交易權(quán)和交易成本[文獻(xiàn)翻譯]
《稅收、交易權(quán)和交易成本[文獻(xiàn)翻譯]》由會(huì)員分享,可在線閱讀,更多相關(guān)《稅收、交易權(quán)和交易成本[文獻(xiàn)翻譯](12頁(yè)珍藏版)》請(qǐng)?jiān)谘b配圖網(wǎng)上搜索。
1、最新 精品 Word 歡迎下載 可修改 原文: Taxes, Tradable Rights and Transaction Costs With respect to market-based policy approaches, it is a widely held view that corrective taxation entails substantial. This conclusion only holds if set-up costs are singled out. It is argued that the prevalence of transa
2、ction costs is largely dependent on the design of the policy instrument, respectively the tax base or the trading regime chosen. Comparative analysis further shows that a cap-and-trade program of emission permits distributed for free, traded on a brokered market and monitored upstream is not only mo
3、re effective, but also likely to entail fewer transaction costs than environmental taxes. Any attempt, in turn, to save the huge information, enforcement and compliance costs incurred by corrective taxation impairs its efficacy by severing the link between the environmental externality and the tax b
4、ase. Basically, there exist four policy instruments to curb pollution: direct regulation, environmental liability, ecological taxes and tradable emission rights. The latter two are similar in the sense that they are market-based instruments that use the price system to internalize environmental dam
5、ages. They compare favorably to the two former approaches because they are flexible and cost-effective as formally demonstrated. Despite their similarity, most countries rely on taxes instead of tradable permits. Since the Kyoto Protocol, however, there is a renewed political and scientific interest
6、 in tradable emission rights. With this rise in public interest, the alleged complexity of the system and subsequent transaction costs are unremittingly criticized. In this article, we will assess the merits of this criticism. Taxes typically carry both an incentive and financial effect. Although t
7、he purpose of Pigouvian taxation is to bring about a change in activity and pollution levels, environmental taxes can be easily conceived as just an alternative source of revenue for the government. Assuming a low treasury preference, public support may have to be won by an environmental tax reform
8、that balances environmental tax revenues with tax cuts elsewhere or provides tax incentives for pollution reduction. However, this does not solve the systemic information problem. When environmental taxes are set too low, suboptimal emission reductions will result. Alternatively, high taxes will cau
9、se unwarranted deadweight losses. Moreover, it has been recognized that the mere existence of an externality does not in itself merit corrective state action. Coase (1960) convincingly argued that, under certain circumstances, the reduction of spill-over effects can be achieved via private negotiati
10、ons. This insight has led to the development of a new policy instrument. Transaction costs: The quest for taxonomy Transaction costs are nowadays frequently invoked to explain institutional, non-market phenomena. Many different definitions appear in the literature, offering various conceptual insi
11、ghts that have not been translated yet into standard cost categories. Therefore, we first take another look at the different definitions offered by various authors from which we will derive an operational and possibly complete taxonomy. The concept of transaction costs was introduced by Coase (1937
12、) to explain why firms exist as an alternative for organizing economic activity by means of exchange transactions across the market. The answer is that firms arise because there are substantial costs involved in using the market. Many different definitions appear in the literature, offering various
13、conceptual insights that have not been translated yet into standard cost categories. Coase was not very explicit about what he meant by these transaction costs. Since different types of costs may be borne by different players at different points in the policy process, a proper classification of tr
14、ansaction cost categories is important to assure that all relevant costs are accounted for. When complete, transaction cost taxonomy may also be helpful in improving policy design and management. According to Dahlman (1979), transaction costs include: –search and information costs, –bargaining a
15、nd decision-making costs, –monitoring and enforcement costs. The economic rationale of institutions lies in the reduction of those costs. This must be interpreted carefully. However, although institutions are, in principle, designed to reduce transaction costs by diminishing uncertainty, they may
16、 not succeed so. New or changing institutions may generate, at any point in time, inconsistencies between competing institutions as well as uncertainty over future institutional changes which, in turn, are likely to lead to increasing transaction costs (Meyer, 2022). Milgrom and Roberts (1992) dis
17、tinguish between two categories of transaction costs. The first type arises from information asymmetries and incompleteness of contracts among parties. The second type stems from imperfect commitments or opportunistic behavior of parties. The OECD has classified transaction costs into two categorie
18、s: –non-policy related transaction costs, which are incurred by parties to voluntary (market) transactions, –policy related transaction costs, which are associated with the implementation of policies. The former include the costs associated with gathering information, negotiating prices, ascerta
19、ining qualities, establishing exclusion mechanisms, organizing collective actions and so on. The latter cover the costs incurred by government in gathering information, planning and designing policies, collecting revenues, distributing payments, and monitoring the outcome of policies. According to
20、Furubotn and Richter (1997), transaction costs involve the use of real resources that could be deployed alternatively elsewhere in the economy or the socioeconomic system. Transaction costs are pervasive at all levels and types of activity and inactivity and comprise the costs of establishing, maint
21、aining, adapting, regulating, monitoring and enforcing rules as well as executing transactions. Interestingly, the opportunity costs of misallocated activities also fit into the category of transaction costs. They make a distinction between three types of transaction costs : –the costs of using the
22、 market (market transaction costs), –the costs of exercising the right to give orders within the organization (managerial transaction costs), –the costs of running and adjusting a political system (political transaction costs). Their taxonomy is the most complete to be found in the literature and
23、 comprises the costs of using the markets as introduced by Coase (1937), the managerial costs put forward by Williamson (1985) and the institutional costs discussed by North (1990). The Furubotn-Richter approach also absorbs the distinction made by Mullins and Baron (1997) between direct transaction
24、 costs (e.g. to initiate and complete a trade) and opportunity costs (e.g. the loss of time and resources due to delay or managerial supervision). Furthermore, transactions entail costs ex ante (e.g. the search and information costs and the costs of negotiating and forming a contract or agreement) a
25、nd ex post (e.g. the costs of monitoring and enforcing a contract or agreement). In practice, however, ex ante costs often coincide with fixed costs and ex post costs with variable costs. It is important to recognize that the two types of costs are usually interdependent. Any attempt to reduce the f
26、ormer may affect the latter. Table 1. Transaction cost taxonomy Transaction costs Fixed (ex ante) Variable (ex post) – Market – Information costs – Insurance costs – Search costs – Signaling costs – Negotiation costs – Contract costs – Managerial
27、 – Set-up costs – Monitoring cost – Enforcement costs – Bonding costs – Political – Lobbying costs – Operational costs – Public support costs – Compliance costs – Enacting costs – Delay costs Source: Based on Furutbotn and Richter (1997). In Table 1, we
28、 offer an extended classification based on the Furubotn-Richter taxonomy that is thought to include all relevant types of transaction costs. This scheme will be used for policy evaluation in the next paragraph. Comparative transaction costs analysis From an ecological and economic perspective, it
29、is clear that tradable emission rights outperform environmental taxes, but the crux of the former system seems the transaction costs it entails. Rao (2021) has suggested that the systems of market based emissions trading; even the well-developed programs in the United States, still have a long way t
30、o go before being effective in any sense because of excessive transaction costs. However, there exists no empirical evidence that transaction costs have prevented trading or significantly affected prices of permits in the United States . Moreover, the occurrence of high transaction costs in emission
31、s trading does not imply that environmental taxation is any less susceptible. As Krutilla (1999) pointed out, the environmental economics literature still lacks a comparative assessment of transaction costs. Environmental taxes Corrective taxation is itself not costless. All relevant transaction c
32、osts associated with environmental taxes will be discussed first. 1. Legislative costs. The decision on the instrument to be applied in environmental policy is formally the competence of the legislator who is supposed to act to further the public interest. But politicians are also influenced by va
33、rious interest groups like the polluting industry, environmental organizations and bureaucracy. 2. Information costs. The literature on environmental tax policy leaves room for a possible net welfare gain of corrective taxation. Containing the amount of information, accuracy relates to business dec
34、isions, however, some information is difficult to obtain. Information costs may further rise when differentiated taxes are to be implemented in accordance, enterprises get maximum benefit from. Finally, environmental pollution is often the result of accidents. Uncertainty also complicates the correc
35、t assessment of expected social costs. 3. Search (planning) costs. First-best analysis expects the tax authority to use personalized. taxes and lump sum transfers since they do not bring additional distortions to the economy. Search costs can be somewhat mitigated, though, when the source can be li
36、nked to the cause of pollution. Taxing substances entails fewer information and search costs compared to personalized or incentive taxation. Search costs can be further reduced when the tax units are already identified. 4. Set-up costs. With the rise of the modern welfare state, the scope of taxat
37、ion has increased dramatically. Consequently, governments have set up large agencies to administer and collect all types of direct and indirect taxes that touch upon almost every aspect of human life (consumption, production, business initiative, work, home and even death). If the new environmental
38、taxes can be levied and collected by an established tax agency, set-up costs are negligible and sunk. 5. Operational costs. Negligible set-up costs do not imply that the costs of tax administration are low. Environmental taxation requires specialized personnel that gather the information discussed
39、above, identifies the correct tax base, determines the optimal tax rate, feeds that information into the existing tax system and, if revenues are earmarked, collects the tax money and establishes a special fund. Although overhead costs can be spread among taxpayers, the costs of operating the tax ad
40、ministration are certainly not negligible and rising with the complexity of the tax law. 6. Negotiation costs. Although corporations and tax authorities often negotiate tax deals that may include environmental taxes and personalized tax deductibles for abatement investments, it is assumed that thes
41、e negotiations are restricted to larger companies and that no tax bargaining occurs among tax subjects. As a matter of fact, taxation is compulsory precisely to eradicate these transaction costs. Hence, negotiation costs are relatively small. 7. Contract costs. No costs are incurred as a result of
42、contracting over environmental. 8. Monitoring and enforcement costs. Because polluters want to reduce the tax burden, they can choose to invest in abatement equipment (if the pay-off exceeds the tax payments), to reduce their polluting activities, to switch to non-taxed activities or to try and esc
43、ape tax payments. Clearly, the environmental tax administration has to perform costly monitoring activities to ensure compliance and enforce tax payments. It is important to distinguish three different problems: tax evasion, tax avoidance and tax delinquency. While tax evasion is a fraudulent effort
44、 to escape a tax obligation, tax avoidance occurs when a taxpayer adapts his behavior in a lawful manner so as to minimize tax payments. Tax delinquency refers to a (temporary) failure to pay the tax obligation. 9. Compliance costs. Administrative mechanisms to prevent tax evasion also lead to cost
45、s made by the taxpayers to comply with the rules. The main source of compliance costs involves recordkeeping and banking operations. Compliance costs can be substantial and are estimated, for example, at 7 percent of total income tax revenue. Conclusion: From this analysis, two main conclusions can
46、 be drawn. First, the transaction costs of environmental taxation are conditional upon the selected tax base. Although set-up costs are relatively low when drawing upon existing tax administrations, the enforcement and compliance costs are likely to be substantial. The latter costs are determined by
47、 the tax rules’ complexity which, in turn, seems a consequence of the linkage principle. The more accurately the tax base is defined, the higher the information costs and subsequent monitoring, enforcement and compliance cost. Secondly, there appears a trade-off between transaction costs and the eff
48、icacy of environmental taxes. Corrective taxation, though desirable in principle, may entail prohibitively high transaction costs that can only be reduced to some extent by sacrificing its original goal viz. matching private and social costs. Source: Lode Vereeck,2022.”Taxes, Tradable Rights
49、and Transaction Costs”, European Journal of Law and Economics No. 20,P199-223. 譯文: 稅收、交易權(quán)和交易成本 關(guān)于以市場(chǎng)為基礎(chǔ)的政策方針,普遍認(rèn)為需要糾正的稅務(wù)量很大。這個(gè)結(jié)論只能在強(qiáng)調(diào)設(shè)置成本的情況下成立。我們認(rèn)為,交易成本的盛行在很大程度上源于選擇的計(jì)稅基數(shù)或貿(mào)易體制。進(jìn)一步的對(duì)比分析表明,排放限額和交易許權(quán)的免費(fèi)發(fā)放,在促成市場(chǎng)交易和上游監(jiān)管上不僅更有效,而且所需要的交易成本可能比環(huán)境稅更少。反過(guò)來(lái),環(huán)境外部性和計(jì)稅基礎(chǔ)聯(lián)系的加強(qiáng),會(huì)削弱任何試圖以糾正稅收來(lái)節(jié)
50、省巨大的信息、執(zhí)行和遵從管理費(fèi)用的方法的效率。 基本上有四種政策工具可以減少污染,它們分別是:直接管理、環(huán)境責(zé)任、生態(tài)稅收和排放權(quán)交易。后兩者是相似的,因?yàn)樗鼈兌际腔谑袌?chǎng),使用改變價(jià)格體系的手段來(lái)減少環(huán)境損失。它們比前兩個(gè)的做法更受人喜愛(ài),是因?yàn)樗鼈冹`活且具有成本效益。雖然它們相似,但是大多數(shù)國(guó)家依靠的是稅收而不是交易許權(quán)。自從京都議定書(shū)后,國(guó)家對(duì)交易排放權(quán)產(chǎn)生了新的興趣。隨著公共利益的提高,復(fù)雜的系統(tǒng)和其隨后的交易成本受到了不斷的質(zhì)疑。 稅收通常既有激勵(lì)的影響,又能產(chǎn)生財(cái)務(wù)效應(yīng)。盡管皮古稅的目的是為了有關(guān)活動(dòng)的減少和污染程度的變化,但是環(huán)境稅通常被理解為只是政府替代收入的來(lái)源。如果國(guó)庫(kù)
51、偏好低,公眾可能支持環(huán)境稅制的改革。他們認(rèn)為可以用稅收減免政策來(lái)平衡環(huán)境稅收或者運(yùn)用到其他地方來(lái)激勵(lì)污染的減少。然而,這并不能解決系統(tǒng)信息的問(wèn)題。當(dāng)環(huán)境稅收過(guò)低時(shí),欠佳減排的問(wèn)題就會(huì)產(chǎn)生。另外,高稅收將導(dǎo)致不必要的損失。此外,人們認(rèn)識(shí)到少量存在的某些外部性原因并不值得讓國(guó)家糾正稅收??扑梗?960)認(rèn)為,在某些情況下,溢出效應(yīng)的減少可以通過(guò)私下談判達(dá)成。這種認(rèn)識(shí)導(dǎo)致了一項(xiàng)新的政策工具的發(fā)展。 交易成本分類(lèi) 如今交易成本經(jīng)常用來(lái)解釋非市場(chǎng)現(xiàn)象。在文獻(xiàn)中出現(xiàn)的許多不同定義,為很多還沒(méi)有被翻譯成標(biāo)準(zhǔn)的成本項(xiàng)目的概念提供了認(rèn)識(shí)。因此,我們應(yīng)該從另外的角度看看不同作者給出的不同定義,這為我們完成分類(lèi)
52、提供了可操作性。 科斯(1937)認(rèn)為交易成本的概念解釋了為什么其在企業(yè)外匯交易過(guò)程中是不可替代的,即企業(yè)活動(dòng)因涉及市場(chǎng)交易所產(chǎn)生的巨額費(fèi)用。許多文獻(xiàn)中也總結(jié)出了各種定義,并且對(duì)于那些尚未被歸類(lèi)的費(fèi)用有著不同的見(jiàn)解。但科斯也明確地表示,他所說(shuō)的不一定就是交易成本的具體意思。 不同類(lèi)型的企業(yè)成本組成并不相同,在不同的政策過(guò)程中,交易費(fèi)用的類(lèi)別是根據(jù)在成本費(fèi)用中所承擔(dān)的重要程度而定的。明確交易成本的分類(lèi)也可以對(duì)改進(jìn)政策設(shè)計(jì)和加強(qiáng)管理有所幫助。 據(jù)達(dá)爾曼(1979)指出,交易成本包括: 搜索和信息成本, 談判和決策成本, 監(jiān)督和執(zhí)法成本。 為了減少這些成本費(fèi)用,必須將其各組成部分解釋清
53、楚。盡管通過(guò)不確定性的原則,各組成部分間因相互協(xié)調(diào)而減少了部分交易成本,但有時(shí)也可能不會(huì)成功。無(wú)論在任何時(shí)候,新產(chǎn)品或更新的產(chǎn)品與原有產(chǎn)品之間都存在競(jìng)爭(zhēng)矛盾,而變革的不確定性,很可能反過(guò)來(lái)導(dǎo)致交易成本的增加(邁耶,2022)。 米爾格羅姆和羅伯次(1992)將交易成本劃分為兩類(lèi)。第一類(lèi)是由于信息的不對(duì)稱(chēng)性和合同中條款的不完整性產(chǎn)生的,第二類(lèi)則是因?yàn)槌兄Z的不完善或者說(shuō)當(dāng)事方的機(jī)會(huì)主義行為而產(chǎn)生的。 另外,經(jīng)濟(jì)組織將交易成本分為兩類(lèi): 非相關(guān)的交易成本,雙方自愿交易(市場(chǎng)政策)導(dǎo)致的相關(guān)成本, 政策相關(guān)的交易成本,執(zhí)行有關(guān)政策所需要付出的成本。 前者包括了收集資料、進(jìn)行議價(jià)、確定素質(zhì)、建
54、立排斥機(jī)制、組織集體行動(dòng)等過(guò)程。后者包括了由政府承擔(dān)的信息收集的成本、規(guī)劃和制定政策、繳費(fèi)收入、分期付款和政策監(jiān)測(cè)下的結(jié)果。 呂博騰和瑞切爾(1997)則認(rèn)為,交易成本是指在經(jīng)濟(jì)制度下,所涉及的可以真正調(diào)動(dòng)資源所產(chǎn)生的費(fèi)用。交易成本涉及很多方面,包括設(shè)備的建立、維護(hù)、調(diào)整和規(guī)范,以及執(zhí)行并監(jiān)督交易活動(dòng)中各項(xiàng)規(guī)則運(yùn)用的全部過(guò)程。有趣的是,在錯(cuò)誤配置下的交易活動(dòng)所產(chǎn)生的成本也能歸入到適合的機(jī)會(huì)成本當(dāng)中。他們根據(jù)交易成本之間的區(qū)別也將之分為三類(lèi): 使用市場(chǎng)(市場(chǎng)交易成本)的費(fèi)用, 組織內(nèi)部發(fā)布命令權(quán)的費(fèi)用(管理交易成本), 運(yùn)行和調(diào)整政治系統(tǒng)的費(fèi)用(政治交易成本)。 這種分類(lèi)是最完整的,他
55、們的文獻(xiàn)中包括了科斯(1937)的有關(guān)介紹、威廉森(1985)提出的管理費(fèi)用的知識(shí)點(diǎn)以及羅斯(1990)提出有關(guān)市場(chǎng)體制方面的成本費(fèi)用的論點(diǎn)。呂博騰和瑞切爾的分類(lèi)方法里也涵蓋了穆林斯和拜倫(1997)所作的直接交易成本(如啟動(dòng)和完成交易)和機(jī)會(huì)成本(如由于延誤或監(jiān)督管理?yè)p失的時(shí)間和資源)的區(qū)別。此外,交易成本需要區(qū)分是在事前(如形成合同或協(xié)議之前搜索信息的費(fèi)用和談判的成本)還是事后(如監(jiān)測(cè)和強(qiáng)制執(zhí)行合同或協(xié)議的費(fèi)用)。但在實(shí)踐中,事前成本往往配合著固定費(fèi)用,而事后成本則為可變費(fèi)用。重要的是要認(rèn)識(shí)到,這兩種費(fèi)用通常是相互依存的,任何試圖減少前者的舉動(dòng)都可能會(huì)影響到后者。 表1.交易成本的分
56、類(lèi) 交易成本 固定(事前) 可變(事后) -市場(chǎng) -信息成本 -保險(xiǎn)費(fèi)用 -搜索成本 -信號(hào)費(fèi)用 -談判成本 -合同成本 -管理 -設(shè)置成本 -監(jiān)測(cè)費(fèi)用 -執(zhí)行成本 -焊接成本 -政治 -游說(shuō)費(fèi)用 -業(yè)務(wù)費(fèi)用 -公共支持成本 -遵從成本 -頒布成本 -延遲成本 來(lái)源:根據(jù)呂博騰和瑞切爾(1997) 在表1
57、中,我們提供了一個(gè)以呂博騰和瑞切爾分類(lèi)方法為基礎(chǔ)擴(kuò)展的方法,其中包括了所有交易成本的類(lèi)型。這個(gè)將在未來(lái)一段時(shí)間內(nèi)被論證。 交易成本比較分析 從生態(tài)和經(jīng)濟(jì)角度來(lái)看,很明顯,生態(tài)稅收要優(yōu)于排放權(quán)交易,其中交易成本似乎是以往的制度政策所造成的。堯(2021)表明,交易成本的存在并沒(méi)有嚴(yán)重影響或阻礙美國(guó)許可證的交易價(jià)格。此外,和生態(tài)稅收相比,擁有高排放權(quán)的貿(mào)易活動(dòng)并不意味著會(huì)產(chǎn)生較少的交易成本。 生態(tài)稅收 稅收本身并非沒(méi)有成本,因此首先將所有與環(huán)境稅收有關(guān)的交易費(fèi)用進(jìn)行討論。 (1)立法成本;制定有關(guān)政策是以促進(jìn)公眾利益為前提的,所有企業(yè)則應(yīng)在法律權(quán)限范圍內(nèi)采取適當(dāng)?shù)男袆?dòng)。但是,領(lǐng)導(dǎo)們也會(huì)受
58、到不同利益集團(tuán)的影響,如無(wú)污染企業(yè)和環(huán)境保護(hù)組織等。 (2)信息成本;提出環(huán)境稅收政策是為了能夠擁有一個(gè)稅收凈收益的可能性。信息的含有量、準(zhǔn)確度都關(guān)系到企業(yè)決策的進(jìn)行。然而有的信息是很難獲得的。區(qū)別各種稅收方式,使企業(yè)獲取最大收益,信息成本就可能進(jìn)一步上升。到最后,往往產(chǎn)生讓人意外的結(jié)果--環(huán)境污染。社會(huì)的不確定性也使得預(yù)期的成本評(píng)估復(fù)雜化了。 (3)搜索(計(jì)劃)成本。首先最好的分析預(yù)計(jì)是稅收機(jī)關(guān)使用個(gè)性化方式。稅收一次性全額轉(zhuǎn)移是因?yàn)樗鼈儾粫?huì)帶來(lái)額外的經(jīng)濟(jì)負(fù)擔(dān)。盡管來(lái)源和污染原因聯(lián)系在一起,但是搜索成本還是可以有所減輕的。同個(gè)性化和激勵(lì)稅收相比,稅收物質(zhì)需要更少的信息和搜索成本。當(dāng)稅收部
59、門(mén)已經(jīng)確定時(shí),搜索成本可以進(jìn)一步減少。 (4) 設(shè)置成本。隨著現(xiàn)代福利國(guó)家的興起,征稅范圍已大大增加。因此,政府已經(jīng)組建了大型機(jī)構(gòu)來(lái)管理和收集所有類(lèi)型的直接和間接稅,這幾乎觸及了人們生活的方方面面(生產(chǎn)、消費(fèi)、經(jīng)營(yíng)主動(dòng)性、工作、家庭,甚至死亡)。如果新的環(huán)境稅可以由建立的稅務(wù)機(jī)關(guān)來(lái)征收,設(shè)置和沉沒(méi)成本則可以忽略不計(jì)。 (5)業(yè)務(wù)費(fèi)用。稅收征管的比率比較低并不意味著設(shè)置成本就可以忽略不計(jì)。環(huán)境稅收需要專(zhuān)門(mén)人員收集資料,結(jié)合現(xiàn)行稅制,討論并確定正確的稅基及最優(yōu)稅率,通過(guò)征收的稅款設(shè)立特別基金。雖然管理費(fèi)用可以由納稅人負(fù)責(zé),但稅收經(jīng)營(yíng)管理的成本仍然不容忽視,其復(fù)雜性也在不斷上升。 (6)談判費(fèi)
60、用;企業(yè)和稅收機(jī)關(guān)經(jīng)常對(duì)有關(guān)交易的稅收進(jìn)行談判,其中可能包括減少生態(tài)稅收和減免個(gè)性化投資的稅收,但這些談判僅限于大公司。事實(shí)上,稅收的強(qiáng)制性正是為了消除這些交易成本。因此,談判的成本相對(duì)較小。 (7)合同費(fèi)用;任何費(fèi)用支出是對(duì)環(huán)境承包的結(jié)果。 (8)監(jiān)測(cè)和執(zhí)行成本;由于污染者要減輕稅收負(fù)擔(dān),他們可能選擇減少設(shè)備投資(如薪酬超過(guò)付稅),減少污染活動(dòng)以轉(zhuǎn)變成非征稅活動(dòng)來(lái)試圖逃避交稅。顯然,執(zhí)行稅收征管必須要密集,這樣才能確保人們遵守稅收制度。其中,最重要的就是區(qū)分三種不同的問(wèn)題:逃稅、避稅和稅收犯罪。逃稅是欺詐性的行為,即努力逃避稅收義務(wù);避稅是納稅人用合適行為、合法的方式,以盡量減少納稅;稅
61、收犯罪是指(臨時(shí))未履行繳付稅款的義務(wù)。 (9) 遵從成本。行政機(jī)制防止逃稅還會(huì)導(dǎo)致由納稅人為遵守規(guī)則付出的成本。遵從成本的主要來(lái)源包括記錄和銀行業(yè)務(wù)。遵從成本可能數(shù)量比較大,但是可以被估計(jì)和預(yù)測(cè)。比如,占稅收總額的百分之七。 結(jié)論:通過(guò)以上的分析,主要可以得出兩個(gè)結(jié)論。首先,稅收可以通過(guò)交易的成本選擇稅基。雖然稅收的設(shè)置成本相對(duì)較低并由現(xiàn)有的稅收當(dāng)局制訂,但要執(zhí)行和遵從成本可能是巨大的。稅收規(guī)則的復(fù)雜性決定了費(fèi)用是可變的,所以,我們可以將它充分利用起來(lái)。其次,交易成本和生態(tài)稅收兩者之間似乎可以相互取舍。調(diào)整稅收,雖然可能帶來(lái)過(guò)高的費(fèi)用,但是能在一定程度上減少其最初的交易成本,也是一種可取的方法。 出處:洛德弗瑞克. 《稅收、交易權(quán)和交易成本》.歐洲法律和經(jīng)濟(jì),2022(20):P199-223。
- 溫馨提示:
1: 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
2: 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶(hù)所有。
3.本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
5. 裝配圖網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶(hù)因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 川渝旅游日記成都重慶城市介紹推薦景點(diǎn)美食推薦
- XX國(guó)有企業(yè)黨委書(shū)記個(gè)人述責(zé)述廉報(bào)告及2025年重點(diǎn)工作計(jì)劃
- 世界濕地日濕地的含義及價(jià)值
- 20XX年春節(jié)節(jié)后復(fù)工安全生產(chǎn)培訓(xùn)人到場(chǎng)心到崗
- 大唐女子圖鑒唐朝服飾之美器物之美繪畫(huà)之美生活之美
- 節(jié)后開(kāi)工第一課輕松掌握各要點(diǎn)節(jié)后常見(jiàn)的八大危險(xiǎn)
- 廈門(mén)城市旅游介紹廈門(mén)景點(diǎn)介紹廈門(mén)美食展示
- 節(jié)后開(kāi)工第一課復(fù)工復(fù)產(chǎn)十注意節(jié)后復(fù)工十檢查
- 傳統(tǒng)文化百善孝為先孝道培訓(xùn)
- 深圳城市旅游介紹景點(diǎn)推薦美食探索
- 節(jié)后復(fù)工安全生產(chǎn)培訓(xùn)勿忘安全本心人人講安全個(gè)個(gè)會(huì)應(yīng)急
- 預(yù)防性維修管理
- 常見(jiàn)閥門(mén)類(lèi)型及特點(diǎn)
- 設(shè)備預(yù)防性維修
- 2.乳化液泵工理論考試試題含答案